Why does money work




















It is usually bilateral, though it can be multilateral, and usually exists parallel to monetary systems in most developed countries, though to a very limited extent. The barter system has a number of limitations which make transactions very inefficient, including:.

Barter : In a barter system, individuals possessing something of value could exchange it for something else of similar or greater value. Despite the long list of limitations, the barter system has some advantages.

It can replace money as the method of exchange in times of monetary crisis, such as when a the currency is either unstable e. It can also be useful when there is little information about the credit worthiness of trade partners or when there is a lack of trust. The money system is a significant improvement over the barter system. It provides a way to quantify the value of goods and communicate it to others.

Money has several defining characteristics. It is:. The use of money as a medium of exchange has removed the major difficulty of double coincidence of wants in the barter system. It separates the act of sale and purchase of goods and services and helps both parties in obtaining maximum satisfaction and profits independently. M1 captures the most liquid components of the money supply, including currency held by the public and checkable deposits in banks.

M1 is the narrowest measure of the money supply, including only money that can be spent directly. More specifically, M1 includes currency and all checkable deposits. Currency refers to the coins and paper money in the hands of the public. Checkable deposits refer to all spendable deposits in commercial banks and thrifts. M1 : The M1 measure includes currency in the hands of the public and checkable deposits in commercial banks. Near monies cannot be spent as readily as currency or checking account money, but they can be turned into spendable balances with very little effort or cost.

Near monies include what is in savings accounts and money-market mutual funds. The broader category of money that embraces all of these assets is called M2. M3 encompassed M2 plus relatively less liquid near monies. In practice, the measure of M3 is no longer used by the Federal Reserve. Mandy deposits the money in a checking account at another bank.

M2 is a broader measure of the money supply than M1, including all M1 monies and those that could be quickly converted to liquid forms. Instead there are several measures, classified along a continuum between narrow and broad monetary aggregates. These round, pierced Chinese coins remained virtually unchanged until the s. An important effect of coins was that governments now controlled the release of money into the market.

They could also manipulate the money supply. This was done by various Roman emperors, who would reduce the precious metal content of Roman coins when they needed money. They figured that if a ton of gold made 10, gold coins, they could have twice as many coins by cutting the gold content in half.

Instead of making the emperors richer, the constant devaluation of Roman coins -- and the resulting instability of the Roman economy -- is one of the factors that led to the fall of the Roman Empire. When Rome fell, most of Europe returned to a more primitive, feudal system of economy.

Throughout the Dark Ages, people became distrustful of coins, and that currency fell out of use. Coinage wouldn't return until the Renaissance. When the U. Mint creates coins, seigniorage -- the difference between the value of money and the cost of its production -- means instant profit. According to the U. Mint, it only takes a few cents to mint a quarter , but the quarter is instantly worth 25 cents.

That difference is the money that keeps the mint running. Paper money was developed first by the Chinese, who used stag skins, bark, or parchment marked with the imperial seal as "bills of payment.

Paper money had trouble gaining acceptance in Europe. Leather money was used around , but only as a temporary substitute when silver supplies ran low. A Swedish bank issued paper money in , but they eventually flooded the market with it, and it lost its value.

The use of paper money really caught on in Europe in the s, when the official bank of the French government began issuing paper money. The idea came from goldsmiths, who often gave people bills of receipt for their gold.

The bills could be exchanged for the gold at a later date. That's an important fact in the development of paper money, because it means that the money represented a real amount of gold or silver that actually existed somewhere.

A piece of money was actually a promise from the institution that issued it either a government or a bank that the institution would give the holder of the bill a certain amount of gold or silver from its stockpile whenever he wanted it. Under this kind of system, the money is said to be " backed by gold. Since money is really just a representation of value, it didn't take long for people to realize they could just send information about money by telegraph or other electronic means, and it was just as "real" as sending the money itself.

After World War II, banks would record information about the day's transactions onto large magnetic reels, which were taken to the regional Federal Reserve Bank. This system eliminated the need for the large denominations that were printed prior to the war to facilitate these large-scale transfers.

Later, wire connections were established between the banks , so the transfer information could be sent directly. By the early s, all transfers between banks and the Federal Reserve were done electronically. One of the long-standing myths about modern currency is that it is backed by the U. That is, you can trade your greenback dollars to the U. At one point, this was true of most paper currencies in the world. However, the U. The obvious question is, "Without gold, what does guarantee the value of our money?

The only reason a dollar, or a franc, or a Euro has any value is because we have a stable system in which people are known to accept these pieces of paper in return for something valuable. Or, as Nobel Prize -winning economist Milton Friedman puts it, "the pieces of green paper have value because everybody thinks they have value.

Many of the words we associate with money today come from ancient uses of currency. Examining where these words came from helps us understand how currency systems developed. Understanding that the value of money is based on our perception of its worth is easier if we look at how that perception can alter the specific amount of that value. Let's say that one American dollar is worth 5 French francs. One day, the U. S dollar to decrease slowly to about 3 francs the U.

The next day, the value of the dollar would likely drop sharply, which it has in similar situations. The government announcement led people to believe that their dollars would be worth less -- therefore, they were worth less. The same effect can be seen in today's stock market , which is another currency system. When a company declares that its profits are down, the value of the company's shares can drop within minutes.

You may have heard your parents or grandparents talk about how different things were when they were your age. It only cost a nickel to see a movie. But currency is actually only a small piece of the monetary economy and just one consideration when looking at the total money supply.

Indeed, most money today exists as credit money or as electronic records stored in databases in banks or financial institutions. But still, the bread and butter of everyday transactions is currency, and that is what we will look more closely at here.

While it may seem obvious, since we all use it on almost a daily basis, the exact meaning of money can also be elusive and nuanced. Imagine you make shoes for a living and need to buy bread to feed your family. You approach the baker and offer a pair of shoes for a specific number of loaves. According to mainstream economics, money alleviates this problem.

It provides a universal store of value that can be readily used by other members of society. That same baker might need a table instead of shoes. In general, transactions can happen at a much quicker pace because sellers have an easier time finding a buyer with whom they want to do business.

Most importantly, money has to be the unit of account, or numeraire , which is a fancy term for the unit that things are priced in within a society. In the U. Once there is a unit of account, people can indeed exchange on credit without the use of physical money. Currency is the physical paper notes and coins in circulation. By accepting the currency, a merchant can sell his or her goods and have a convenient way to pay their trading partners. There are other important benefits of currency too.

The relatively small size of coins and dollar bills makes them easy to transport. Consider a corn grower who would have to load a cart with food every time he needed to buy something. A farmer who relies on direct trade, for example, may only have a few weeks before his assets spoil. With money, she can accumulate and store her wealth. However, currency has taken a number of different forms throughout history.

In many early societies, certain commodities became a standard method of payment. The Aztecs often used cocoa beans instead of trading goods directly. However, commodities have clear drawbacks in this regard. Depending on their size, they can be hard to carry around from place to place. And in many cases, they have a limited shelf life. These are some of the reasons why minted currency was an important innovation.

As far back as B. Metallic money in the form of coins made from precious metals such as gold, silver, or copper have been commonplace since early civilization.

Other forms of currency that have existed include large circular stone in the Pacific Islands, cowrie shells in pre-modern America, tobacco leaves, measurements of grains or of salt, or even cigarettes and packages of ramen noodles in prisons. More recently, technology has enabled an entirely different form of payment: electronic currency. Today, electronic payments and digital money is not only common, but has become the most important and ubiquitous money form.

However, it retains its worth for one of two reasons. Inflation of the currency, if it becomes excessive, causes people to want to get rid of their money as quickly as possible. Inflation, and the rational way citizens react to it is bad for the economy. Business activity sharply declines because of this. The belief in money and the steady value of the currency are not innocuous things.

If citizens lose faith in the money supply and believe that money will be worthless in the future, economic activity can grind to a halt. This is one of the main reasons the U. Federal Reserve acts diligently to keep inflation within bounds—a little is actually good, but too much can be disastrous. Money is essentially a good, so as such is ruled by the axioms of supply and demand.

The value of any good is determined by its supply and demand and the supply and demand for other goods in the economy. A price for any good is the amount of money it takes to get that good.

Inflation occurs when the price of goods increases—in other words when money becomes less valuable relative to those other goods. This can occur when:. The key cause of inflation increases in the supply of money.

Inflation can occur for other reasons. These kinds of situations are rare. For the most part, inflation is caused when the money supply rises faster than the supply of other goods and services. To summarize, money has value because people believe that they will be able to exchange this money for goods and services in the future.

This belief will persist so long as people do not fear future inflation or the failure of the issuing agency and its government. Actively scan device characteristics for identification. Use precise geolocation data.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000